Showing posts with label supply and demand. Show all posts
Showing posts with label supply and demand. Show all posts

Wednesday, November 17, 2010

Question from a teacher about the elasticity of supply

Question:  My students are currently studying demand, supply, and price.  When we were discussing the elasticity/inelasticity of demand and supply, a question arose regarding if any good/service exists which possesses both perfectly inelastic demand and supply.  I've given it considerable thought and the only goods/services I could think of which would fit the criteria are utilities (ie. electricity), water, waste water treatment, etc.  I believe demand for these goods/services is inelastic as would be supply (no substitutes, few suppliers, oligopolistically competitive market structures, etc.).   This line of reasoning would apply to their stock as well.  Are there any other examples?  Am I correct or totally off-base?   

Response:
You are not totally off-base but your question mentions a common misunderstanding when it comes to the determinants of the elasticity of supply.

In your question you state "perfectly inelastic supply and demand".  To that question the answer is no, both functions would be vertical and I know of no good that is perfectly inelastic in demand and supply.   One often cited example of perfectly inelastic demand is insulin.  Yet insulin is relatively elastic in supply.
Are there goods that are highly inelastic in demand and supply? Yes, but also keep in mind that the usage of elasticity you are referring to is a general, relative measure where one good is compared to another.  Examples would be goods that have very few substitutes on the demand side and are very difficult to produce on the supply side (technologically intensive, raw materials are difficult to get quickly, production techniques cannot be modified easily).  A good example is gasoline relative to, say, cigarettes or insulin.  All are highly inelastic on the demand side but gasoline producers are not able to respond as quickly to a price increase as cigarette or insulin producers.  Therefore gasoline has a more inelastic supply than cigarettes or insulin.

The difficulty for students when it comes to the elasticity of supply is to explain the concept without using an elasticity of demand determinant (like available substitutes, time frame for purchase, or proportion of budget).  Elasticity of supply is the responsiveness of the producer to a change in the good's price and is therefore determined by production flexibility -ability to quickly and easily/cheaply increase or decrease quantity supplied.  The fact that a product is elastic or inelastic to consumers does not necessarily mean anything when it comes to the elasticity of supply.  Hence substitutes, few suppliers, or oligopolistic market structures are not determinants, by themselves, of inelastic supply.  A monopolist could produce a good that has an elastic supply... think of Google's near monopoly over internet advertising.  If the price for internet ads were to increase, it would be relatively easy for Google to respond with an increase in the quantity supplied.

Utilities are inelastic in demand but depending on time of year or day, may be fairly elastic in supply.  Again, what's important is that elasticity is a relative concept.

Monday, August 10, 2009

ECONOMICS LESSON: The Economics of Price Gouging

Given the current economic climate in the United States, many citizens are worried about their financial well-being. When citizens are confronted with rising prices on staple products, necessary items, and generally inelastic goods, they turn to the media, government, or anyone who will listen to their complaints. We see reports in the newspaper, or on television, about "price gouging" and unsympathetic businesses hurting middle class America. But is so-called "price gouging" really a bad thing? Or, is government control of prices really doing more harm than good?



This clip by John Stossel of ABC's 20/20 was made in the wake of Hurricane Katrina. But its message and reasoning are founded in Adam Smith's view of a free market economy, and certainly apply to America's current economic situation. It offers a great introduction to the topic of price ceilings and government intervention in the economy.


So, what is a PRICE CEI
LING?
  • A price ceiling is a legal maximum price that can be charged for a good or service.
  • When a price ceiling is set below the equilibrium price, it will cause shortages.
  • Price ceilings occur when government is dissatisfied with the outcomes of free markets.
The figure below represents an artificial rent ceiling, such as the rent control policies of New York City in the 1950s:
  • When government limits the price of rental units to $400 per month, the suppliers are only willing to provide 3000 units. The market, on the other hand, is demanding 6000 units. As you can see, the Rent Ceiling, represented by the red line, has resulted in 3000-unit shortage. In addition, when 3000 units are available to rent, consumers are willing to pay $625 per month. Since the price established by government is only $400, landlords are experiencing a loss of $225 per month, per unit. That is a $675,000 loss per month by all property owners in this market.
  • Some questions to think about...
  1. What are some additional economic and societal effects of this situation?
  2. How might third-parties be affected by this?
Points to Ponder
  • Government can also set prices greater than the equilibrium price created naturally by the market. This type of price control is known as a PRICE FLOOR and results in surpluses. Suppliers are willing to supply at the artificially high price, but consumers won't buy.
  • Government doesn't have to set a specific price for shortages or surpluses to occur. Interventions such as trade barriers, tariffs, and subsidies can have the same effect.